The Role of Commodity Value in Inconvertible Credit Money A Contemporary Unoist Perspective

 




PDF version 

1. Introduction

The quantitative easing policy implemented after the 2008 global financial crisis reflects an exogenous view of the money supply, consistent with monetarist policies. However, even during quantitative easing, endogenous money supply theories began to emerge. This resurgence is evident in some central banks’ publications (Saito 2023; McLeay et al. 2014; Deutsche Bundesbank 2017). Modern Monetary Theory (MMT) has also contributed to popularizing endogenous money supply theories among the general public. In “mainstream” economics, New Keynesian and Neo-Wicksellian frameworks occupy a central position as part of the New Consensus, where the money supply is assumed to adjust endogenously at the interest rate determined exogenously by the central bank (Lavoie 2022, ch. 4; Monvoisin and Rochon 2006; Fontana et al. 2020).

Endogenous money supply theories explain only that the money supply adjusts endogenously to the demand from non-bank economic agents, but do not clarify what money is based on or what money itself is. Therefore, despite the apparent broad agreement on the concept of endogenous money supply, there are significant variations within these theories.

Moreover, many of the endogenous money supply theories require certain historical conditions, such as the suspension of gold convertibility and the existence of central banks. Among these theories, why inconvertible money can circulate is also a major point of contention. Some proponents of these theories argue that money becomes fiat money, capable of circulating by government decree. Others emphasize that money cannot circulate solely by government decree and that money is issued by bank credit and extinguished by repayment. In contrast, some traditional Marxian economists viewed inconvertible money as government paper money. However, other Marxians argue that inconvertible money is also credit money, based on commodity value. There are numerous other theories as well, but addressing all of them is beyond the scope of this paper.

 

This paper aims to distinguish between the endogeneity and exogeneity of money supply, on the one hand, and the endogeneity and exogeneity in the logical emergence of money, on the other. The latter refers to whether money logically emerges endogenously within the commodity market or is exogenously injected by non-market authorities. Following this distinction, the objective of this paper is to elucidate a theory of money in which both the supply and the emergence of money are endogenous, by further developing the recent Unoist approach.

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 presents a 2 × 2 matrix with axes representing the logical emergence and supply of money to clarify the dual interpretations of the endogeneity and exogeneity of money. Section 3 discusses the Commodity Theory of Money as developed by the recent Uno school. Section 4 examines the “Inter-Capital Organization” theory, developed by recent Unoist scholars, as a condition for endogenous money supply. Finally, Section 5 concludes this paper.

 

2. The 2 × 2 matrix: logical emergence and supply of money

Though the term "endogenous money" is often used in the context of money supply, the principle in Marxian economics also interprets the endogeneity of money as its logical emergence from the commodity economy. For example, Shigeru Yamaguchi, an Unoist scholar, argued that the endogenous perspective asserts that money arises from the commodity world, whereas the exogenous perspective claims that money is injected externally into the commodity economy. The value-form theory in Marxian economics, which derives money from the commodities, aligns with the endogenous stance (Yamaguchi 2000: 240).

As another example, Costas Lapavitsas (Lapavitsas 2017) uses the term "endogenous" in two different senses when referring to money. In chapters 2 to 6, he uses “endogenous” to describe how the quantity of money is adjusted or supplied to meet market demand. In chapters 9 and 12, he uses “endogenous” to refer to the logical emergence of money in market trading, particularly in the context of his critique of neoclassical economics.

Considering these two meanings of “endogenous” in relation to money—its logical emergence and its supply—we can create a framework, as shown in Table 1, to classify the diverse views of money.

Table 1. Classification of money theories.


Below, I explain the four conceptual categories in a simple sequence: a) to d). Yet it is important to note that these categories are conceptual, and there are intermediate positions between them.

a) Exogenous money supply theories

Exogenous money supply theories posit that the government or central bank can inject money at will and adjust the quantity of money, regardless of initial market conditions. These theories postulate that changes in the money supply can lead to changes in prices and/or production volume.

Regarding the emergence of money, these theories assume that government legal tender laws allow money to circulate.

b) Metallism

Metallism views physical gold (or silver, etc.) as the sole proper money. In terms of money emergence, metallism is considered to be endogenous because gold is inherently a commodity, making metallism one of the commodity theories of money. However, metallism typically does not recognize inconvertible credit money as commodity money. Therefore, regarding the contemporary inconvertible credit money, it does not belong to the commodity theory of money.

Metallism is exogenous regarding the money supply. Yet, money supply in metallism view might be endogenous in some scenarios: gold production, hoarding (hoard and dishoard), and promises to pay in proper metallic money. However, even if gold production can increase the money supply in response to demand, it cannot decrease it. Hoarding cannot quickly respond to rapid and widespread changes in the demand for money. In a capitalist economy, promises to pay in gold were mainly issued through bank credit. When the promise to pay in metallic money is issued without limit, unfettered by the quantity of metallic money, it is based on the borrowers’ assets rather than on metallic money itself and thus aligns with commodity money in cell d), as will be discussed in Section 3.

c) Endogenous money supply theory

In this theory, the money supply is evidently endogenous, but the issue lies in the logical emergence of money. Some proponents argue that the money supply can be endogenous because money is not a commodity, and emphasize government decree as the origin of money. Others focus on the efflux and reflux of money but leave unresolved the question of its logical emergence.

 

d) Commodity theory of money

Michiaki Obata, a leading Unoist scholar, redefines “commodity money.” According to him, commodity money is rooted in commodity value and can be classified into two types: material money and credit money (or debt-type money). These forms of money are illustrated in Figure 1.

Figure 1 Classification of forms of money



 Obata 2009: 48

 

In Figure 1, money is divided into two categories: commodity money, which is based on commodity value, and chartalist money, which is not based on commodity value but dependent on the government decree. Only commodity money can circulate within a commodity economy.

Material money circulates as physical objects of the commodity, while credit money is characterized by commodity value being self-sustained in the form of a claim (Obata 2009: 46–47). Material money aligns with metallism, as shown in Figure 1, cell b). Credit money corresponds to the commodity theory of money, as depicted in Figure 1, cell d). Credit money, issued through banking channels, is grounded in commodity value. The concept of commodity value in credit money will be explained in detail in the next section.

 

3. Logical Emergence of Money: The Commodity Theory of Money

3.1 Is Money Creation from Nothing?

The endogenous money supply theories claim that banks can create new money, primarily in the form of deposit currency, without accepting deposits in advance. This method of issuing money is often referred to as money creation (or credit creation) from nothing (or ex nihilo).

However, Yamaguchi argued that credit creation does not imply that newly created money exceeds reserves; rather, it means that newly created money is backed by a credit claim (Yamaguchi 1984: 45). The relationship between credit money, reserves, and credit claims is illustrated in Figure 2 with a balance sheet.

Figure 2 The expression of Yamaguchi’s theory of credit creation with balance sheet

Asset

Liability and capital

Reserve

Bank note and deposit

(Credit money)

Credit claim

Capital

 

The “from nothing” view considers the relationship [ Credit Money > Reserves ] in amount. In contrast, Yamaguchi argues for [ Credit Claim = Credit Money ]. In other words, credit money is created backed by the credit claim, not “from nothing.”

By extension, it can be said that the credit claim itself is backed by the borrower’s future repayment. Furthermore, the borrower’s future repayment is secured by the borrower’s current and/or future assets. These relationships are illustrated with three balance sheets in Figure 3.

 

 

Figure 3 The Structure of Bank Money

Borrowers

Bank

Deposit holders

Assets

Liabilities

Assets

Liabilities

Assets

Liabilities

Assets

(commodity value)

Liabilities to bank

Credit claim

Deposit liabilities

 

Deposit currency

Net worth

 


 

3.2 The Approach to Explaining the Logical Emergence of Money

There are two potential methods for explaining the endogenous emergence of money:

 

a) Using the Value-Form Theory: This method demonstrates that the value expression of multiple commodities is concentrated on bank liabilities (or a specific bank's liability), thereby making those bank liabilities the general equivalent. This approach is orthodox within the principles of Marxian economics, as seen in Marx's The Capital (volume 1, chapter 1, section 3). However, I have previously attempted this method in Iwata (2022, 2024), and it requires a long and complicated explanation. Therefore, I will omit it in this paper.

 

b) Using Balance Sheets: This method statically demonstrates the commodity foundation of bank money.

3.2 The Commodity Foundation of Bank Money

As mentioned earlier (in section 3.1), the foundation of bank money lies in the commodity value of the borrower's assets. To understand this, it is essential to grasp the concept of a “commodity” precisely.

By definition, a commodity includes the uncertainty of its sale, constrained by its specific use-value. Therefore, the realization of its value is only potential. The bank, through credit assessment of the borrowers, reflects the potential value in its own bank money, which is not constrained by its specific use-value. The bank’s assessment is validated when the borrower's commodity is sold (i.e., when its value is realized). In other words, when the bank provides credit and issues money, the borrower's commodity value is pre-validated as money. When the borrower sells their commodities and repays the bank, the bank money is ante-validated[1]. Between pre-validation and ante-validation, there is credit risk associated with credit money.

While deposit holders (bank money possessors) have claims against the bank, they do not have a real right (in rem) to the assets of the bank's debtors. The bank pre-validates the value of the borrower’s commodities and provides the deposit holders with money (deposit currency) backed by the commodity value of the borrower’s assets.

It should be noted here that what backs bank money is not only the quantity of commodity value but also the use-value, which enhances the salability of commodities. The bank deliberately selects the borrowers with more salable commodities through its credit assessment. Thus, the bank indirectly aggregates and controls many salable commodities. Borrowers seek bank money circulating in the market for repayment, while bank money holders seek the commodities held by the borrowers in exchange for bank money. This complementary relationship is facilitated by the bank’s credit assessment.

Consequently, bank money is based not only on the quantity of commodity value but also on the use-value of commodities. Such a view is the commodity theory of money.

 

4. Endogenous Money Supply in the “Inter-Capital Organization”

4.1 The Essence of Banks: Circulating Debt as Money

Banks’ profits primarily derive from interest earned on credit operations. In these operations, the bank creates its liabilities, which can circulate as money, to acquire credit claims. Therefore, banks strive to maintain the value of their debt as money and to expand circulation of their bank money.

4.2 Credit Creation by Individual Banks within the Banking System

It is often said that credit creation is possible within the entire banking system, but not by an individual bank, because an individual bank may lose reserves due to the payment request for deposits created through credit. In such a situation, an individual bank must prepare some amount of reserves in advance before lending, which constrains the endogenous supply of money.

There was a complex debate within the Uno School regarding reserves. In simple terms, Yamaguchi argued that securing payment reserves in advance is not crucial for banks. The primary concern for banks is the credit risk associated with loan claims, while the liquidity risk of insufficient payment reserves is merely a secondary issue (Yamaguchi 2000: 134-135). He mainly gave two reasons:

 

1) As long as the claims are sound and there is repayment of principal and interest, the repayment will exceed the liabilities by the amount of interest, thus negating the need for payment reserves (ibid., 134).

 

2) Even if there is a payment exceeding the reserves, as long as the discounted bills as claims are sound, reserves can be replenished through rediscounting with other banks (ibid., 145).

4.3 Payment Reserves and Interbank Lending

In this section, we assume the simplest case where there is no requirement for a statutory reserve ratio, and all payments are made through the transfer of deposits within a bank or between banks. Furthermore, we assume that there is no credit risk and that the interbank market functions smoothly.

In this scenario, a payment from Bank A corresponds to a receipt at another bank, which we will refer to as Bank B. Therefore, if Bank B extends credit to the paying Bank A, Bank A does not need to hold payment reserves in advance, as shown in Figure 4.

Figure 4 Excess Payments through Borrowing: Excess Receipts through Lending

 


This credit extension automatically offsets the payment and receipt, eliminating the need for the movement of reserves between banks. Consequently, each bank can endogenously issue money through credit without securing reserves in advance. However, this presumes an overly harmonious relationship, which contrasts with the Uno School’s logic that traditionally emphasizes the uncertainties inherent in the circulation process. Yamaguchi’s explanation limits the analysis of the market structure to the essence of capitalism. However, to analyze the concrete structure[2], it is necessary to apply the concept of “Inter-Capital Organization” theory, which has been recently developed within the Uno School.

4.4 Reserves in the Inter-Capital Organization

Although the meaning of “Inter-Capital Organization” varies by scholar, it can be briefly summarized as follows: To reduce the burden of uncertainty in the circulation process, multiple competing capitals establish special contracts for trading. Table 2 shows the correspondence between simple transanction and organized or structured transanction.

Table 2 comparison between simple,  and organized or structured transanction

simple transanction

organized or structured transanction

spot, small lot, distributed sporadic transanction

continuous, large lot, concentrated transanction

When applying the theory to banking organizations with an endogenous money supply, the following two factors are possible: the horizontal space for concentrated transactions and preemptive measures. These factors are based on the pursuit of profits by individual competing capitals and do not conceptually overlap with each other[3]. Table 3 compares the two factors.

Table 3 Two factors forming banking organization to facilitate reserve adjustment


The horizontal space for concentrated transactions is formed as a result of individual banks attempting to offset payments with receipts from other banks. This space centralizes spot transactions, enabling the offsetting of reserves and facilitating smooth lending and borrowing. Consequently, individual banks can supply money endogenously as long as there is no credit risk. Such a concentrated market does not exist in the case of ordinary commodities.

Preemptive measures refer to contracts made in advance to secure reserves in preparation for potential future shortages. This corresponds to a credit line. The bank providing the credit line can expand the circulation of its deposit currency. The bank to receive the credit line can supply money endogenously within the credit line.

5. Conclusions and perspectives

The endogenous money supply theories were critical tools again
st mainstream economics. However, as views for endogenous money supply become more widespread, it becomes increasingly important to understand the differences within these theories.

This paper examines the distinction between endogeneity and exogeneity from two perspectives: logical emergence and money supply. While a comprehensive review of all miscellaneous theories of money is beyond its scope, this study aims to elucidate the endogenous theory from both perspectives using the Unoist approach.

In modern capitalism, money is issued by bank credit and held as bank liabilities. As long as money is issued through banking operations, it is backed by the borrowers' ability to repay, which is based on the salability of their commodities, either current or future. This relationship exists regardless of whether the money is convertible or inconvertible. Therefore, money issued by bank credit is essentially commodity money.

The importance of the commodity basis of money lies not only in the quantity of value but also in its use-value. Through credit assessment, banks indirectly aggregate and control many salable commodities. Thus, both in terms of value and use-value, bank money is aligned with the commodity theory of money.

This paper argues that the condition for an endogenous money supply is the inter-capital organizations, which are formed by competing banking capitals to increase their own profits.

Based on these conclusions, the following perspectives offer a deeper exploration of the theoretical implications and future directions for understanding money and banking.

The relationship between banks and commodities in the commodity theory of money reveals the theoretical possibility for banks to indirectly penetrate the commerce and production processes. This penetration aims at strengthening the salability of commodities. The inter-capital organization theory has the potential to theoretically explain the role of central banks and various banking organizations through competition among banking capitals. Furthermore, this theory enables the explanation of the formation of private organizations among financial institutions, operating outside the central bank-led system.

References

Deutsche Bundesbank. 2017. The role of banks, non-banks and the central bank in the money creation process. Deutsche Bundesbank Monthly Report, April 2017.

Baronian, Laurent. 2023. Money and capital : a critique of monetary thought, the dollar and post-capitalism,   Abingdon: Routledge.

Evans, Trevor. 1997. Marxian Theories of Credit Money and Capital, International Journal of Political Economy, 27(1).

Fontana, Giuseppe, Riccardo Realfonzo and Marco Veronese Passarella. 2020. Monetary economics after the global financial crisis: what has happened to the endogenous money theory? European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies, 17(3).

Iwata, Yoshihisa. 2021. Even inconvertible money is credit money: Theories of credit money in Japanese Marxian economics from the banknote controversy to modern Uno theories. Journal of Tokyo Keizai University: Economics 311.

Iwata, Yoshihisa. 2022. A new method of value-form analysis based on a claim on commodity set [in Japanese] Political Economy Quarterly 59(1).

Iwata, Yoshihisa. 2021. Towards the New Theory of Commodity Money on Inconvertible Credit Money. Journal of Tokyo Keizai University: Economics 321.

Kanai, Yuichi. 2023. Can the Central Banks Create Money? Monetary History of Credit System [in Japanese]. Nagoya: University of Nagoya Press.

Lapavitsas, Costas. 2017. Marxist Monetary Theory: Collected papers. Leiden: Brill.

Lapavitsas, Costas. 2013. Profiting without producing: How finance exploits us all. London: Verso.

Lavoie, Marc. 2022. Post-Keynesian Economics: New Foundations, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Pub.

Marx, Karl. 1996. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy Volume I, in Marx–Engels Collected Works (MECW) Volume 35, New York: International.

McLeay, Michael, Amar Radia, and Ryland Thomas. 2014. Money in the modern economy: An introduction. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 2014 Q1.

Monvoisin, Virginie and  Louis-Philippe Rochon. 2006.  The Post-Keynesian consensus, the new consensus and endogenous money, in Gnos, Claude and Louis-Philippe Rochon, eds.,  Post-Keynesian Principles of Economic Policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Pub.

Obata, Michiaki. 2009. The Principles of Political Economy [in Japanese]. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.

Saito, Yoshihiko. 2023. Why did central banks publish papers on the endogeneity of the money supply? [in Japanese]. Osaka Keidai Ronshu 74 (1).

Sakura Genron Kenkyu Kai. 2019. Redesigning the Principle of Political Economy [in Japanese]. Tokyo: Pal Publishing.

Uno, Kozo. 1977. Principles of Political Economy: Theory of a Purely Capitalist Society. Brighton. Sussex: Harvester.

Yamaguchi, Shigekatsu. 1984. The Theory of Financial Mechanism, [In Japanese.] Tokyo: Tokyo Daigaku Shuppankai.

Yamaguchi, Shigekatsu. 2000. Problems in the Theory of The Structure of Finance [in Japanese]. Tokyo: Ochanomizu Shobo.



[1]  On pre-validation and ante-validation, see Evans (1997: 29).

[2] Yamaguchi classified the role of Marxian economic principles into elucidating the essence of capitalism and providing tools for analyzing real capitalism.

[3] The conceptual derivation of non-overlapping foundational factors is based on the Morphic Approach by Obata.



コメント

人気の投稿