Theories of credit money in Japanese Marxian economics: 2 Okahashi in Banknote controversy
A.
Okahashi in Banknote controversy
“Banknote
controversy” on inconvertible banknote arose in Japan from the mid-1950s to the
early 1960s. The gold standard suspension in the Great Depression of the 1930s.
Then, after World War II, the advanced capitalist economies recovered and
restored the exchangeability between main currencies. However, the
convertibility to gold remained unrecovered. Can the currency circulate
normally without convertibility? The controversy began with the proposition by
Tamotsu Okahashi that “even inconvertible banknote is also credit money, not
state paper money.” State paper money is fiat money, which has no value in
itself and can circulate only by state force. Although money is not necessarily
tangible such as banknotes, Okahashi and his contemporaries mainly treated the
banknote as money with finality. Therefore, the banknote in this controversy
means the money itself.
Many in the
Banknote controversy disagreed with Okahashi’s theory, arguing that inconvertible
money is state paper money that can circulate only by state compulsion.
Okahashi’s argument did not spread. Therefore, it is essential to quote some
paragraphs of Okahashi’s book.
A.1 Creation of
credit money
According to
Okahashi, credit money arises from bill transactions. In the commodity economy,
obtaining a commodity needs paying money. However, the delivering money need
not occur at the same time as receiving the commodity. It is also possible to
receive the commodity first and pay the money after a certain period of time.
The promise to “pay later” is the bill of exchange, which is the basis of
credit money. If the bills cancel each other out, the proper money is no longer
needed. Thus, “they act absolutely as money.” (Marx [1981] p.525)
Okahashi
explains the creation of credit money is as follows:
In the monetary
economy, receiving something must correspond to giving another. There can be no
receiving without giving anything. Therefore, only if a person contributes to
society can he receive what deserves his contribution. his mutual reward
relationship is always strictly secured in the monetary economy. Thus the
commodity circulation consists of giving and receiving through money. However,
this mutual reward relationship does not necessarily coincide. … In a particular stage of development of the circulation, the producer
can receive something without giving anything. In the production relationship that
allows him to delay giving for a certain period of time, a credit relationship
enables receiving before giving. There, money becomes the means of payment.
The credit
relationship gradually develops with money as the means of payment and gives
the bill a monetary function. The bills become so-called commercial money.
Commercial money arises from the mutuality of giving and receiving credit
between producers and merchants. Such complicated mutual credit relationships exist
in the roots of the bill circulation. Therefore, the bills can circulate as
means of payment or purchase instead of the proper money. As long as the
receivables and debts cancel each other out, no proper money is needed. In this
way, bills can function instead of money because the mutual credit between
producers and merchants establishes a corresponding reward relationship between
giving and receiving. Thus, in general, commercial bills are the first
alternative to the money function as a means of payment. (Okahashi [1957] pp. 109-110)
The credit money
is, in essence, a bank bill or bank deposit issued by bill discounting and
circulates in place of a private bill. It is the money as a payment instrument
peculiar to the banking system, based on the circulation of bills, and has
developed from commercial money. Just as the money arises from commodity
circulation, commercial money arises from developed commodity circulation with
credit relationships. When banks emerge, the credit money arises through the lending
of credit by banks. (ibid., p. 137)
Okahashi
explains that credit money circulates instead of a commercial bill. Then, The
commercial bill is used instead of the proper money. The proper money is a kind
of commodity and is selected among all the commodities. As long as the credit
money is issued on the basis of bill circulation, it is neutral to the economic
process. (This neutrality will be described later in section A.4.)
Thus, the matter
is not whether convertible or inconvertible, but how the banknotes are issued. When
they are issued not based on bill circulation, they are non-proper banknotes.
Because inconvertible
banknotes issued by bill discounts and securities-backed loans can contract
depending on the situation of circulation, they would not remain in circulation
forever. In contrast, when inconvertible banknotes are thrown into circulation
with unproductive public bonds as collateral, they cannot contract and remains
in circulation as a legal means of payment forever. Indeed, such inconvertible
banknotes remaining in circulation obey the laws of state paper money. Nevertheless,
the inconvertible banknote not originally based on the circulation of paper
money cannot be the same as state paper money. Since the proper banknote is “not
based on monetary circulation, that of metallic or government paper money, but
rather on the circulation of bills of exchange” (Marx [1981] p. 525), it is a
means of circulation peculiar to “commercial circulation” (ibid., p. 529), not
one for general circulation.
Nevertheless,
banknotes have entered the general circulation as legal tender in place of state
paper money because some of them come to be issued on the basis of the money
circulation. Thus, the problem is not whether convertible or inconvertible, but
rather whether the banknote circulates as bill circulation or money circulation
(Okahashi [1957] p.208).
Clearly,
Okahashi shows that the nature of banknotes depends on the financial asset
which the bank receives at their issuing.
A.2 Multiple
ways to issue banknotes and three laws of circulation
Okahashi
explains the multiple ways to issue banknotes and three laws of circulation:
Although the
banknotes are not prescribed as the Bank of Japan’s bills, they are related to
different circulations through the different properties guaranteed. Therefore,
depending on different properties, banknotes flow into circulation according to
different laws and are constrained by these laws. Under the gold standard, just
because the banknotes are obligated to convert to gold does not mean all the
convertible banknotes conform to the same law. Similarly, after suspension of
the gold standard, just because the banknotes become inconvertible does not
mean all the “inconvertible” banknotes are inconvertible paper money, that is,
state paper money. Moreover, conversely, all the inconvertible banknotes do not
have the same effect on circulation. They differ in the circulation law by the
way to enter circulation or the guaranteed properties. Whether the banknote is
legally convertible or inconvertible, the banknote is always tied to and
constrained by gold. Therefore, in this sense, there is no monetary system
other than the gold standard. It does not matter whether the conversion of banknote
to gold is legally obligated or suspended (ibid., pp.214-215).
It is
challenging to understand Okahashi’s claim that the gold standard exists even
without conversion. However, it can be understandable by considering that the
banknotes can circulate on the basis of the bill circulation without gold
conversion. Thus, despite the suspension of the conversion, the gold standard
system could continue.
The following
figure shows the explanation of Okahashi about three laws of circulation.
Table A-1
Laws of circulation |
In Marx’s “The Capital” |
Guaranteed property・Backing assets, By Okahashi |
arise from… |
Laws of the circulation of bills of
exchange |
v.3, p.525 |
commercial bills、bank accepted
bills |
means of payment |
laws of metallic circulation |
v.2, p.192,400 |
securities, gold, non-commercial
bills |
means of circulation |
Laws of circulation of paper money |
v.1, p.224 |
state bond, unsecured loan to the state |
metal circulation |
The money based on the bill circulation increases
or decreases, depending on the demand of the commerce. The money based on the metal
circulation arises in exchange for things possessing value, such as gold and
securities, which possess value within or without circulation. The money based
on the paper money circulation is valued as long as it remains within circulation
instead of the metallic money. If its quantity increase more, its value
declines
Okahashi explains
the three ways as follows:
Firstly, banknotes
guaranteed by commercial bills, bank accepted bills, and other bills rest on
the re-discount of commercial bills and are the proper banknotes that follow
the law of bill circulation. However, when the bills securing banknotes are not
directly based on commercial trade, the banknotes obey the law of metal
circulation. When the bills securing banknotes are insolvent and taken over by
the government, the banknotes obey the laws of paper money.
Secondly, banknotes
guaranteed by government bonds do not stand on the general circulation. They follow
the laws of paper money circulation. In addition, when banknotes are issued by
loans collateralized by state bonds or unsecured loans to the government, they also
follow the laws of paper money circulation.
Thirdly, the
banknotes guaranteed by bullion of gold and silver follow the laws of metal
circulation. … Nevertheless, the banknotes by purchasing bullion are still just
commercial money (Okahashi [1957] p.215).
According to
Okahashi, banknotes issued by lending on the securities or the bullion follow
the laws of metal circulation because the money the borrower paid to buy them
is just taken over by bank lending. In
short, no money increases. (ibid., p.195)
It may be
difficult to understand that “the banknotes by the purchase of bullion are still
just commercial money.” Since commercial money is a direct payment promise by
the issuer (ibid.,p.195), the banknote issued in exchange for gold is the
commercial money for the bank. The bank’s liability becomes the credit money, when
the bank gives credit by handing over its liabilities at sight in exchange for
the commercial money of the debtor by bill discount (ibid., pp. 115-116).
A.3 Currency prescribed as the legal tender and compulsory currency
Okahashi
emphasizes that legal tender provision is not a panacea for the circulation of
money. The legal tender provision only legally confirms that banknotes based on
the circulation of bills are actually accepted as means of payment. Not all
legal tenders can circulate. Okahashi explains as follows:
The basis of the
circulation of monetary substitutes lies in each aspect of circulation. Just as
state paper money originates from the circulation of metal, the proper banknotes
originate from the circulation of bills and stand on the means of payment of
money. On the other hand, since the state paper money arises as a function of
the means of circulation of money, it directly enters the general circulation
as an intermediary for commodity circulation. However, since the proper
banknotes arise in place of commercial bills, they appear in commercial
circulation in the same way as commercial money. They are liabilities at sight,
very trusted, have a more comprehensive circulation than personal bills, and
seem as if they were cash (general means of circulation). However, banknotes
are still just bills, and the circulation of banknotes never stands on the
circulation of money. The provision of the banknote as legal means of payment
stands on its nature of bill circulation. Banknotes are accepted legally
because banknotes actually circulate based on the bill circulation. They are
fundamentally different from the state paper money as proper paper with “compulsory
power.” The state paper money does not circulate
depending on the fiat of the state. Instead, the metal circulation enables the state
paper money to circulate as a symbol of value in a limited amount. Similarly,
banknotes also do not circulate by the provision of legal tender. Instead, the
provision is just a “legal confirmation” that banknote is already widely
circulated instead of the money. The legal means of payment and the mandatory
circulating power are essentially different. Even if the banknote becomes legal
tender, it neither has “the mandatory circulating power” nor loses its essence
as a bill. Its nature does not change after the suspension of conversion.
Unlike state paper money, the inconvertible banknotes still circulate on the ground
of the nature of bills. (ibid., pp. 124-125)
Banks acquire financial
assets and issue banknotes (credit money) as their liability. The asset
supports the value of the banknote as guaranteed property. If the property is the
bill that is certain to be repaid in the future, the banknote is the proper
banknote. However, the banknote backed by other properties is non-proper.
A.4 Neutrality
of credit money and denial to credit creation
Famously,
Schumpeter maintained that credit creation creates new money as purchasing
power from nothing. The producer with new purchasing power gives birth to a new
product or a new production method. Interestingly, Okahashi’s denies such an
effect of credit creation on the real economy and claims the neutrality of
credit money. He explains the reason as follows:
Credit money as additional money appears through
various processes. … In whatever way it appears, the created credit money is a
new form of additional fictitious capital for the issuing bank, as for the portion not
guaranteed by gold or cash reserve on hand. However, even if it is privately additional
capital, it is socially neither “additional” capital nor additional net demand
as extra money. This additional credit money is the claim to the existing
social products made by economic development. Even though the sums of created
credit money “appear newly created side by side with the existing sums”
(Schumpeter [1951] p.99), there is already a contribution to social products
that should correspond to additional credit money. The money has been newly “created”
to realize the price of the additional social products. Unlike Schumpeter argues, it is never “certificates of future services or
goods yet to be produced.” (ibid.,p.101) Moreover, it is not the credit means of
payment, especially “created” without contributing to social products (pp. 173-174).
The following
figure shows a comparison between Schumpeter’s credit creation and Okahashi’s
denial of credit creation.
Fig. A-1
Schumpeter’s credit creation
Okahashi’s denial of credit
creation
In Schumpeter,
the money created by banks allows borrowers to hire workers and buy means of
production to make new products. Credit creation has a significant impact on
the economic process.
In contrast, in
Okahashi, the commodity the borrower buys already exists, and newly created
credit money realizes the value of the seller’s commodity. The new credit money
only corresponds to the value of the existing commodity. Thus, credit money is
neutral to the economic process.
コメント
コメントを投稿