Theories of credit money in Japanese Marxian economics: 2 Credit creation and endogenous money supply theory in Uno theory
B. Credit money in Uno school and
controversy
B.1 Kozo Uno’s criticism of Marx’s credit theory
Logically, Marx
starts credit theory by dividing one capital into ownership of capital and
function of capital. Each becomes a money capitalist and a functioning
capitalist as their personalization. In other words, money capitalists exist apart
from functioning capitals. Credit is the lending and borrowing of capital
between the two parties. The relationship between the two determines the level
of interest rate. Note that the interest rate does not follow the same law as
the production price of commodities. Marx mainly treats the money supply as
exogenous, although he also refers to elastic money supply as fictitious
capital (ex. Marx[1981] p.589). Marx asserts that money is gold and the source
of loan capital is outside the functioning capital. If the money supply is
inelastic, it would be easier to explain the catastrophic crisis.
However, Uno
criticized Marx for separating money capitalist from functioning capitalist
(Uno [1977] p.120). The principle of political economy assumes that each
capital tries to maximize its profit. Therefore, it cannot suppose the money
capitalists who are satisfied with a lower rate of interest although they could
earn a higher rate of profits with their capital.
Instead, Uno argued that parts of the money capital
are temporarily idle for various reasons in the capital reproduction and are sources
of funds to lend(ibid., p.110). They lose the use-value for the owner but will be needed soon. Thus, such
money capital temporarily becomes a commodity as use-value for others. When the
funds (money capital) are lent, its rent is the interest rate. In short, interest
is the price for the use of funds for a definite period of time. (ibid., pp.121-122)
Uno, as well as Marx, assumed that the supply and demand of money (fund) determines
the interest rate level. However, unlike Marx, Uno emphasized that the loan
funds are from temporarily inactive funds in the capital reproduction process
and increase or decrease in the business cycle.
Uno further
utilizes his theory of interest rate to explain the crisis. When the profit rate
declines at the end of the boom due to wage increase, idle money capital will
decrease, and the interest rate will rise rapidly. Then, when the interest rate
increases above the profit rate, a crisis happens.
Thus, Uno
inherits Marx’s way of the exogenous money supply, although he refers to
issuing banknotes depending on the bank’s reserve money (ibid., p.111).
However, when
credit money can increase elastically by lending, money holders need not be
supposed as sources of funds. In addition, the interest rate cannot be
determined by the supply and demand of the money. Instead, it should be
determined by the competition among capitals and the general rate of profit in
the capitalist economy.
B.2 Development of the theory of credit creation: Yamaguchi
Yamaguchi, a theorist of Uno school,
explains that credit creation is creating current purchasing power in
anticipation of future return. He theoretically argued that credit creation takes
place at commercial credit before bank credit.
He indirectly criticizes the
concept of fictitious capital of Marx. The debt of a bank beyond the reserve money
of the bank is not fictitious, but the whole debt is backed by the claim of
banks.
Let us illustrate to make the following explanation easier to understand.
Fig. B-1
Yamaguchi explains the credit
creation as follows:
Recently, even
among Marxian economics, credit creation is often used more than just as a
popular word. Its contents are still variously understood by theorists, and its
theoretical provisions have yet remained ambiguous. It generally means creating
unreserved liability that functions as the purchasing power. In other words,
traditionally, it means the banks increase lending by creating the debt
(banknotes or deposits) beyond their cash reserves (sometimes called primary
deposits). In addition, it has been thought to be unique to bank credit, and
its internal relationship with commercial credit has been largely unquestioned.
Such a conventional
view of the bank’s credit creation emphasizes that it creates money beyond its
reserve. … However, even if the created banknotes and deposits exceed its
reserves, they are made by loans such as bill discounts and backed by the loan
receivables, not cash reserves. In other words, bank liabilities are the
purchasing power based on the fact that loan receivables are repaid after a
certain period of time. Therefore, the essence of what is referred to by the
term “credit creation” is not the money creation beyond the reserve, which is
superficial and less meaningful. Instead, it should be a substantive function
of creating current funds by anticipating future acquisition of funds.
Thus, credit
creation has already emerged in commercial credit before bank credit, and the
internal relationship between credit creation by banks and commercial credit
becomes clear. In other words, the bank credit only lifts the restrictions on
the credit creation in the commercial credit and substitutes for the commercial
credit. Commercial credit is the basis of credit creation by banks. The credit
creation through commercial credit is more direct than bank credit in
anticipating future fund reflux. The bank credit also stands on the
anticipation of the future money return, but the anticipation is indirect.
Therefore, the bank reserve seems to support the bank credit. For that reason,
the conventional view may have emphasized the creation of money beyond reserve
money (Yamaguchi [1984] pp. 44-46).
Note that the difference between commercial
credit and bank credit. The debtors’ money acquisition backs both commercial
credit and bank credit. Nevertheless, bank credit seems to be backed by the bank’s
reserve.
Let us consider the
substitution of a bank for commercial credit. At first, suppose that capital A
is short of money reserve due to temporary stagnant sales of its commodities.
To continue production, capital A can buy raw materials from capital B in
postpaid credit. The assets of capital A increase by the price of raw
materials, and its debt increases by the same price simultaneously. On the
other hand, capital B (seller, creditor) receives claims (commercial bills) on
A instead of cash.
Fig. B-2
after credit trading
Fig. B-3
The creditor
anticipates that the debtor’s commodity will be sold and monetized in the
future and allows the postpaid dales. The creditor does not lend money directly
to the debtor.
Subsequently,
suppose the banking capital buys the claim from the creditor and pays with
self-addressed liabilities at sight, such as deposits or banknotes.
Fig. B-4
The deposit currency
in the creditor’s asset is backed by the claim in the bank’s asset. Finally, it
is backed by the future money from the future sale of the commodity in the
debtor’s asset. Subsequently, the creditor can buy commodities with the
deposits. Thus, credit money emerges from commercial credit and circulates
without the proper money.
Consequently, Yamaguchi
argues that the circulation of convertible banknotes mainly stands on the smooth
repayment of the claims held by the issuer’s bank.
Yamaguchi
explains the conversion and the credit money:
Firstly, let us consider promissory notes and
convertible banknotes. Although the bill is materially a piece of paper, it is
received by the commodity seller and acts as a de facto means of purchasing.
The rationale is that the receiver trusts the debtor will pay in the future. The
basis of the trust is the debtor’s smooth reproduction process. The convertible
banknotes are received, for the moment, because they are liabilities at sight
(money claim), and their payment is trusted.
Nevertheless, the basis of trust is that the bank
or the banking organization would smoothly receive repayment from their financial
assets. More generally, the convertible banknotes can circulate as de facto
money, based on the smooth process of social reproduction (Yamaguchi [2000] pp.194-195).
B.3 Self-contained
Credit theory of money: Yoshida
Satoru Yoshida had worked for the Japanese
Bankers Association for a long time and then became a university professor. He was
a practitioner economist rather than a theorist but exchanged with economics
scholars, including the Uno school.
Uniquely, he asserts that all the existing
money is credit money endogenously issued by bank lending. In addition, he denies
other exogenous money such as gold and fiat money. Usually, the theorists of
endogenous money supply assume fiat money supplied exogenously by central banks
or governments, apart from credit money by commercial banks. However, not just
commercial banks, Yoshida argued that the money issued by the central bank is
also credit money, not fiat money. Yoshida summarizes as follows::
In modern times,
all money (central banknotes, deposit currency) is credit money. (Auxiliary
money is not a problem here, although legally referred to as “money”). “Credit”
of credit money is “credit,” not “trust.” Credit money is money that occurs and
disappears in a credit relationship. However, this definition of credit money
is subject to many objections.
Banks provide
financial intermediation while creating money as deposits through credit
creation. Then, banks must replenish their reserves. The reserve is supplied by
the central bank as a bank of banks. (Reserve is needed after, rather than
pre-existing reserve enables credit creation. The Phillips-style theory of
multiplier credit creation is reverse causality. )
For deposits to
function as money, systems such as bill clearing and exchange trade are formed.
(These are deposit transfer systems.)
The essence of a
central bank is a “bank of banks.” Banknotes and central bank deposits are only
issued through financial transactions. Even inconvertible banknotes are not
fiat money.
People get
banknotes through the withdrawal of deposits. Deposits are promises to pay
banknotes, but deposits must exist first to increase banknotes.
The Central bank
accommodates to demand for banknotes and central bank deposits. However, how it
accommodates (financial adjustment) can determine short-term market interest
rates and affect general rates of interest. This is the basis of monetary
policy (Yoshida [2008] p.15).
Interestingly, Yoshida
uniquely uses the term “credit.” Usually, “credit” of credit money means “to
trust the promise of the bank issuing credit money to pay the proper money.”
That is, the holder of credit money trusts the bank. However, Yoshida uses the
term “credit” to mean “to trust the debtor receiving the credit money to pay
off the debt.” That is, the bank trusts the debtor. By interpreting in this
way, Yoshida can discuss credit money without any proper money.
The commercial
banks are obliged to hold the central bank money preparing for payment of
deposits. Then, can the central bank money circulate by becoming fiat money by
the legal tender provision? Yoshida goes back to the convertible banknotes and
explains the basis of circulation of central bank money regardless of
conversion.
Were the
convertible banknotes able to circulate due to convertibility? If so, inconvertible
banknotes could circulate only by the provision of legal tender. However, even
if a currency is forced to circulate as legal tender, it could not spread, or
even dollarization could occur when suffering from severe inflation. When even
inconvertible banknotes are managed well, they can circulate without any
problems. Certainly, convertibility was necessary to enhance the credibility of
banknotes, but was not the actual basis for circulation the ways to issue
banknotes? In short, at first, there are credit relationships in economic
transactions. Then, as the substitute of the relation, the credit money is
issued, whether a banknote or a deposit currency. In other words, does the
valid rationale of circulation exist in the issuance and return of money grounded
on reproduction? (Yoshida [2002] p.78)
“The ways to
issue” means that fiat money is issued by government spending while credit money
is issued by lending. Fiat money has no backing assets, whereas banknote as
credit money holds a backing asset such as financial claims and bonds. As long
as the backing asset is sound, the banknote can circulate.
Even inconvertible
banknotes do not lose their debt nature. Here, Yoshida appreciates the well-known
explanation of the debt nature of inconvertible banknotes in Nishikawa[1984].
Nishikawa says that the bank’s debt is paid off by banknote holders buying
commodities in the market rather than directly requesting the central bank to
pay off (Nishikawa [1984] p.47). Nishikawa assumes the debt nature of the
inconvertible banknote is not a direct relationship between debtor and creditor
but the central bank’s debt to the entire commodity society. Based on this
explanation by Nishikawa, Yoshida explains as follows:
Price stability
(maintenance of currency value) is essential for the issuer of inconvertible
banknotes to guarantee their ability to pay off. It is an obligation of private
law for the issuer of inconvertible banknotes to maintain the trust of banknote
holders rather than a public obligation. Financial textbooks say the goals of
monetary policy are stabilizing prices, balancing international payments, and
maintaining full employment. Nevertheless, it is said that the final
destination should be stabilizing prices because of maintaining the debt nature
of banknotes, including other debts of the central bank (Yoshida [2002] p.128).
Just as the commodity
producer should guarantee the quality of his commodity, the bank should maintain
the magnitude of the value of the credit money it issues. The magnitude of the
value of the money is the reciprocal of prices.
However, Yoshida’s
theory has the problem of discussing credit money without explaining the money.
In short, it is “a theory of credit money without any theory of money.
B.4
Yoshida-Yamaguchi Controversy
Yamaguchi
criticized Yoshida’s theory of credit money as follows:
“The endogenous
money supply theory,” which Yoshida seems to support, denies that the pre-existing
money is lent and maintains that, conversely, money arises by the lending. Indeed,
money arises from the loan relationship, and similarly, the modern inconvertible
central banknote also comes into existence through the credit mechanism.
However, since lending is a lending of money, we should first assume the
concept of money before the lending. If we consider that money arises from money
lending, we will fall into eternal circular reasoning. After the circular reasoning
is cut off, the theory of endogenous money supply can hold. In other words,
theoretically, “the cash money is the premise.” Nevertheless, this does not
mean agreement with the Phillips-style theory of credit creation. (Yamaguchi[2008]pp.84-85)
In response,
Yoshida wrote:
It shows the
theorist’s way of thinking, but actually, such cash money never exists. Nevertheless,
“theory” resting on such cash money seems to diffuse. It would ground credit
theory on inconvertible banknotes (fiat money) with mandatory circulating power.
Not to say, Yamaguchi would agree with the “theory.” Hopefully, an approach
“breaking the circular reasoning” will emerge. (Yoshida [2008] p.24 )
B.5 How
to break the circular reasoning of credit money
As criticized by
Yamaguchi, Yoshida’s theory of credit money is circular reasoning that “a
promise to pay money is money.” If credit money is a promise to pay something, what
is this “something”? If we present something, we can cut off the circular
reasoning.
(1) The first way
is to “cut off with legal tender.” The government stipulates what can pay off
the debt between private agents, and the government provides it as legal tender.
Because all the agents owe the monetary debt by buying commodities in the
commodity society, the legal tender can circulate even with no value. The
government does not necessarily issue it. The promise to pay it is credit
money.
(2) The second
is to “cut off by tax collection.” The government stipulates what can pay off tax.
Because all the agents owe tax obligations to the government, The means to pay tax
can circulate even with no value or with no mandatory circulating power. The
government does not necessarily issue it. The promise to pay it is credit
money. This way is often used by Chartalists.
(3) The third is
to“cut off with gold money.”
As the theory of value-form shows, gold is selected as a money commodity among all
commodities that have value in themselves. Because gold has its value and all
agents can exchange all commodities with it, it can circulate. The promise to
pay it is credit money. However, as Yoshida says, gold is no longer money.
(4) The fourth is
to “cut off with commodity money.” The way emphasizes that the issuer
of credit money has financial assets backed by commodity value. We explain it in the next section.
コメント
コメントを投稿