Theories of credit money in Japanese Marxian economics: 3 Commodity theory of money in modern Uno theories
C. Commodity
theory of money in modern Uno theories
C.1
Credit money as commodity money
Obata, a current
representative theorist of modern Uno school, explains “commodity money in a
broad sense” in his textbook of the principle of political economy:
The commodities have
specific use-value, such as linen and coat. There is no general use-value.
Since the commodity has some “specific” use-value, its “general”
exchangeability for others is constrained. Conversely, as long as a commodity
is “valued,” any commodity has the qualification to become money potentially,
that is, the nature of money. Therefore, money is a special commodity based on
the nature of money inherent in commodities. The position to think this way is the
commodity theory of money. The theory of the value-form of the commodity
inevitably reaches the commodity theory of money (Obata [2009] p.44).
Commodity money consists
of material money and credit money. The material money is defined as follows:
Material money is
the money which the physical body of the specific commodity becomes as it is
(ibid., p.45)
Obata explains
the credit money as follows:
The commodity
theory of money is often said to consider only material money or metal money as
money. However, it is a misunderstanding that arises from equating commodities
with things. Originally, commodities
are in a particular state of things with use-value for
others and always have value on the backside. The commodity theory of money
explains money on the basis of the value of commodities. The theory does not
argue that money is made of physical material without the value of commodities.
Commodity money includes material money but is not reduced to it. Then, the
commodity value can be externalized and self-supporting in the form of a monetary
claim. The credit is money becoming self-sustaining in the form of a claim
(ibid., pp. 46-47)
Theoretically, all the commodities express
their value by one thing, and their exchangeability concentrates on the same
thing. The thing becomes commodity money. Nevertheless, money can take two
forms: material money and credit money. Marx and Uno have explained the
material money sufficiently. Obata discusses the polymorphism, that money takes multiple forms, in Obata [2013]. Although he shows the basic concept
of credit money, he does not sufficiently succeed in a detailed argument.
He classifies multiple forms of money as
follows:
ibid., [2009] p.
48
Importantly,
commodity money consists of material money and credit money. Currently, the
fiat money does not circulate except auxiliary money in
a limited amount. Chartalist
money stands on the chartalist theory of money. Obata explains the :
The idea opposed to the commodity theory of money is the chartalist
theory of money. The chartalist theory assumes that even non-commodities can be
thrown as money from outside the market. If the material of the chartalist
money is paper, it is the state paper money. However, regardless of material,
it is widely called fiat money. The theory that the agreement of people can
create money independently is a kind of the chartalist theory. Because credit money and state paper money are
usually made of the same material, paper, they are grouped as paper money, opposed
to metal money. However, it is a mess due to the appearance of money. The
commodity theory of money can explain both material money, including metal
money, and credit money. On the other hand, fiat money, including state paper
money, stands on the chartalist theory of money and is conceptually
different from credit money (ibid., pp. 47-48).
From the above quotation, the meaning of Fig.
C-1 is clear.
Here, let us develop the theory of credit money
backed by the issuer’s assets. It continues from (4) the way to “cut off with commodity money” at the
end in section B. The structure of credit money be illustrated in the balance
sheet as follows:
Fig. C-2
Because credit
money is issued by bank lending, the bank holds a claim on the borrower. The
borrower has assets that guarantee repayment. The assets may be commodities for
sale, production means generating revenue, or the ability to receive wages or
tax revenues. It is easy to show the basis of the value of credit money in this
static manner.
However, it is
challenging to elucidate the logical genesis of credit money, as with the
value-form theory. Currently, theorists of the Modern Uno school propose several
methods to elucidate credit money’s genesis based on the value of a set of multiple
commodities without gold or fiat money.
C.2 Determination
of the level of interest rate
Credit money is issued by banks, which are a
kind of capital pursuing valorization. Therefore, the interest rate should be where
banking capitals can gain the general rate of profit. Here, Obata shows the relation between the interest rate and profit
rate as follows:
Bank net profit
rate = {(Q
× i - Q' × i' ) – k – d } / P
= the general rate of net profit of industrial capitals
Where: Q
is loan quantity, i is lending interest rate, Q’ is deposit quantity, i’
is deposit interest rate, k is circulation cost (various expenses in bank
business ), d is bad debt loss, and P is bank’s equity capital (ibid., p. 238)
The interest
rate is determined, so that bank’s profit rate in this formula is at the same
level as the general rate of profit of industrial capitals. In this way, the
mechanism of money creation can be explained in a self-contained manner in the
capital pursuing profit. However, to fully understand this relationship, it is
necessary to know the circulation cost, net profit rate and gross profit rate,
and downward dispersion of net profit rate, which modern Uno theories propose.
コメント
コメントを投稿