The Difference Between Italian and French Monetary Circuit Theory

Introduction 

Monetary Circuit Theory (MCT) explains that money is created through bank lending, circulated between firms and workers, and destroyed through the repayment of loans. The term “circuit” refers to this flow of money. The creation of bank money for firms is termed "initial finance," while the firms' retrieval of money for repayment through sales or the issuance of securities is termed "final finance."

Methodologically, MCT draws on the approaches of Keynes (non-neutrality of money in “Treatise on Money”) and Marx, particularly the M–C–M' form. MCT criticizes the neoclassical theory in which money supply is exogenous and the price and interest rate are determined by the relation between the demand and supply. In contrast, MCT claims that money is supplied in response to firms' demand to pay wages for production. 

As a type of macroeconomic theory, MCT aggregates different economic agents into three sectors: firms, workers, and banks. Therefore, transactions within the same sector are typically canceled out. This leads to a difference with Marxian economics on theoretical explanation of bank credit. Marxian economics claims that, within commercial credit among industrial capitals, the capital specializing in credit operations eventually becomes banks. However, the aggregation in MCT cancels out the inter-capital commercial credit. Therefore, MCT presupposes the existence of banks from nothing. Moreover, MCT denies the existence of commodity money with intrinsic value and asserts that money is merely a valueless sign created from nothing through bank lending. Thus, this view has difficulty explaining the historical existence of physical commodity money (Graziani 1990,11). However, many proponents focus solely on the contemporary monetary system.

MCT developed in two distinct schools: French MCT and Italian MCT. Although they are often presented as similar, key differences exist. Understanding these differences provides a deeper insight into MCT. While other strands exist—such as the Dijon–Fribourg group—I focus on the French and the Italian schools.

For example, The Elgar Encyclopedia of Post-Keynesian Economics includes two separate entries: “Monetary Circuit – French School” (Parguez 2023) and “Monetary Circuit – Italian School” (Veronese Passarella, 2023). These entries contain critiques of each other's positions. According to them, major points of difference include the role of the state and the treatment of the price level. A further, less clearly defined difference concerns how firms acquire production goods.


The Role of the State

Parguez (2023) emphasizes the role of the state in two respects. First, money is issued not only through bank lending but also through government expenditure (ibid., 280). Second, he argues that money requires state endorsement. Parguez and Seccareccia (2000) write:

“Because of the state endorsement of these debts as the ultimate guarantor of their liquidity, it would be wrong to conceive holders of bank liability as bank creditors. In a sense, given its endorsement by the state, one can legitimately argue that money is always fiat money, even when the state is not issuing it and the role of the state is marginal” (ibid., 105–106).

The French MCT is thus primarily concerned with the institutional nature of money and with monetary and fiscal policy. It overlaps conceptually with Neo-Chartalism or Modern Monetary Theory (MMT).

By contrast, the Italian MCT excludes the state from the basic circuit model (Veronese Passarella 2023, 281). It focuses on the sovereignty of firms over the working class. Like the French school, it maintains that money is just a token and not a commodity, and that it must be issued as bank debt through lending to firms, forming a triangular transaction: firms, banks and workers (Graziani 1990, 11). However, the Italian school denies the privilege of money issuance through government expenditure (ibid.). According to this view, ordinary fiscal policy can only redistribute income within each class; redistribution between classes requires direct political intervention (Veronese Passarella 2023, 281–282). For this reason, the state is left out of the core theoretical structure.


The Price Level

The French MCT generally assumes that prices are fixed. This assumption is based on factors such as mark-up pricing over costs, the aim of long-term profit targets, and the influence of Sraffian price theory (Parguez 2023, 280; Lavoie 2023, 9; Godley and Lavoie 2007, 264). In this framework, unsold goods are held as inventories, representing the credit balance between banks and firms before securities are issued. The idea that prices are determined by market demand and supply belongs to neoclassical theory.

In contrast, Graziani—the central figure of the Italian MCT—allows for flexible pricing, where firms adjust prices in response to expenditure of workers and to investment decisions made by firms. He proposes the following formula:

 

  • P = market price of output
  • s = saving propensity of wage earners
  • b = proportion of total output that firms decide to purchase
  • w = money wage rate
  • N = total employment
  • π = average productivity of labor
  • B = total value of bonds issued by firms
  • i = interest rate on bonds

 

Y = C + I

Y, C and I can be expressed respectively as:

Y =  πNp,  C = c (wN+iB),  I = bπNp

Therefore,

πNp = c (wN+iB) + bπNp

This leads to the following expression for the price level:



The term in square brackets represents the money cost of output (Graziani 1990, 23), composed of wage costs (wN) and interest costs (iB) paid to workers who hold the firms' securities.

This equation shows firms’ sovereignty in the pricing process, which allows them to adjust prices to reduce the real wage.

When firms decide to purchase more output (i.e., b increases), the price P rises. The workers, who received a predetermined nominal wage, can buy fewer goods, as firms later set prices in a way that reduces the real value of wages and allows them to obtain more goods for investment. This case is one of involuntary forced investment. However, if workers voluntarily decide to save so that the saving rate s equals b, the price increase is contained, and workers’ saving covers firms’ investment (Graziani 2003, 151–152). Although this price level does not imply full market clearing as assumed in neoclassical theory, it does suggest that prices are responsive to demand and supply conditions—unlike the fixed-price assumption in the French school.


Purchase of Production Goods

In the French MCT, current output is bought based on the consumption and investment decisions made in the previous period (Parguez 2023, 280). As a result, the French literature often uses overlapping circuits of different periods to resolve theoretical issues, such as the "profit paradox."

By contrast, the Italian MCT often completes the process within a single circuit. The purchase of capital goods—that is, investment—is always covered ex post through current workers’ saving (Veronese Passarella 2023, 281). Since firms cannot repay the value of unsold goods, that amount remains as outstanding money in the banking system, or is covered by workers' purchases of firms’ securities. Thus, this approach stays within a single circuit without requiring overlapping circuits.


Another School: The Dijon–Fribourg Group

The term "French school" can be somewhat misleading, as there is another monetary circuit school within the French-speaking world: the Dijon–Fribourg Group.

“A Handbook of Alternative Monetary Economics” (2006) includes a chapter titled "French Circuit Theory," written by Claude Gnos, a member of this group. The Dijon–Fribourg Group includes Bernard Schmitt, Claude Gnos, Alvaro Cencini, and Sergio Rossi.

This school places a strong emphasis on double-entry bookkeeping and frequently uses balance sheets in its theoretical framework. For example, in the aforementioned article, Gnos criticizes the argument made by Parguez and Seccareccia (2000), stating that, from the perspective of double-entry accounting, “Depositors are creditors of banks and ultimately the creditors of bank borrowers” (Gnos 2006, p. 94). The Dijon–Fribourg Group is often regarded as being closer to the Italian MCT than to the French MCT associated with Parguez.

 It is impossible to discuss all topics in this article, but it may offer some clues for further understanding of monetary theory.


Reference

Gnos, Jean-François. “French Circuit Theory,” in A Handbook of Alternative Monetary Economics, edited by Philip Arestis and Malcolm Sawyer. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2006.


Graziani, Augusto. “The Theory of the Monetary Circuit.” Économies et Sociétés, série Monnaie et Production, no. 7 (1990): 7–36.

Graziani, Augusto. The Monetary Theory of Production. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2003.

Lavoie, Marc. “Wynne Godley’s Monetary Circuit.”  Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 44:1, 6-23 2021.

Parguez, Alain. “Monetary Circuit – French School.” In Elgar Encyclopedia of Post-Keynesian Economics, edited by Louis-Philippe Rochon and Sergio Rossi. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2023.

Parguez, Alain, and Mario Seccareccia. “The Credit Theory of Money: The Monetary Circuit Approach.” In What Is Money?, edited by John Smithin, 101–123. London: Routledge, 2000.

Veronese Passarella, Marco. “Monetary Circuit – Italian School.” In Elgar Encyclopedia of Post-Keynesian Economics, edited by Louis-Philippe Rochon and Sergio Rossi. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2023.


コメント

人気の投稿