スキップしてメイン コンテンツに移動

注目

日英Meetup in London

   今、在外研究でロンドンに来ているが、諸般の事情で家族と日本語で話す他に、話す機会がほとんどない。 ネットで日本人とイギリス人のMeetupを探していってみると以下のものがよかった。他にもいくつかあるが、行ったことがないのでわからない。 日本語会話の会  パブで何時間か三々五々に分かれて話すというもの。日本語を話したがっているイギリス人(正確にはロンドン在住非日本人)が多く来るので、話しやすい。生活や旅行などいろいろ情報も聞きだすこともできる。イギリス人7割、日本人3割くらい。イギリス人の多くは日本語の日常会話には支障がない。日本人同士の会話にもなるので、生活情報には重要なこともある。イギリス人は、こちらが英語で話せば、英語の練習にも付き合ってくれる(人によるが) 。 月1回第1火曜、予約不要。参加費£3、食事つきはさらに食事代。その他、不定期にイベントあり。今年で25周年だそうで、しっかりとしたウェブサイトもある。 29歳以上の日英交流イベント  29歳以上、となっているが、こちらの方が若い人が多く、騒々しい。不定期開催。月に2回以上はあると思う。参加費£2。 このイベントの前に同じ会場で、 言語交換イベント が開かれる場合がある。こっちは参加費1ポンド。日本人1人、イギリス人(正確にはロンドン在住非日本人)1人、または2人で話をする。20分くらいで人を入れ替える。こちらの場は落ち着いて話ができる。この二つは Dillonという人が主催者。 情報収集が目的の場合はあらかじめ質問を決めておかないと何となくで終わってしまう。英語の勉強が目的の場合は、イギリス人が日本語を話したがっているので、こちらが勝手に英語を話し始めることが必要。参加者はだいたい性格の良い人が多い。こちらの変な英語でも理解しようとしてくれる。ロンドンで英語が分からないとストレスがたまるが、こうした場は逆に日本人が優位になる。

Turnover of industrial capital, commercial and bank credit: modern Unoist approach 2. Turnover of the industrial capital




2. Turnover of the industrial capital  

2.1 Premises of Turnover in Marx’s Capital

Marx analyzed turnover as consisting of production and circulation. He sometimes discussed shortening the total turnover time by reducing the circulation period (e.g., Marx 1973, 659; Marx 1978, Chapter 14). After introducing the concept of continuous production through added capital in Chapter 15 of Capital Volume II, the focus shifted to how circulation length affects the amount of capital that must be advanced and the volume of idle money (Marx 1978, 358). 
In Chapter 15, Marx made several assumptions to clarify the nature of industrial capital, differs from the general formula for capital, M-C-M’. We regroup the ten assumptions in Saros 2008 (195) as follows.  

A. Basic assumption on turnover. 

A-1. Production is continuous (Marx 1978, 334)
A-2. No fixed capital is assumed (Marx 1978, 354)
A-3. All production time is working time (Marx 1978, 334)
A-4. Surplus value is set aside (Marx 1978, 334)
A-5. The same amount of capital is advanced weekly (Marx 1978, 334)
These assumptions help simplify the analysis. "Continuous" production refers not only to uninterrupted production but also to production at the same scale. Assuming no fixed capital means that the replacement period of fixed capital is excluded. The same scale of production must continue “on the given basis of fixed capital” (Marx 1978, 335). Hiroshi Hidaka rightly noted that although fixed capital is assumed away, it plays a hidden role in driving production, as it compels continuous operation (Hidaka 1977)
The assumption about using the capitalist’s own capital relates to the connection between turnover length and the amount of capital advanced.

B. Assuming away credit 

B-1. Money is gold(Marx 1978, 213)
B-2. No credit relations exist (Marx 1978, 336)
B-3. In the first turnover period, production is funded entirely by the capitalist’s own capital (Marx 1978, 336)
Marx allowed for relaxing these assumptions when analyzing credit (ibid., 357).

C. On the circulation, especially the sales

C-1 Normal business conditions are assumed(Marx 1978, 109, 335)
C-2 Circulation time consists only of selling; there is no buying time(Marx 1978, 326)
Fluctuations in turnover time are mainly due to variations in selling time. The assumption of “normal business conditions” enables the use of average circulation time.

2.2 Literature in Japan on turnover

Although Marx examined several numerical examples in Chapter 15, Japanese Marxian economists from around 1950 clarified three main methods (Tanaka 1996):
– Interrupted production method 
– Unilateral continuous production method
– Overlapping (parallel) continuous production method 

Assume that 100 units of money are injected into production each week for six consecutive weeks, and products worth 600 are sold all at once after a three-week circulation period.

A. The interrupted production method 

In the interrupted production method, production stops and resumes only after the products are sold.



The composition of productive capital, money capital, and commodity capital changes over time as follows:  

Marx noted such an interrupt production in the circuit of P…P and referred to Chinese handicraftsman (Marx 1978, 181-182) In this method, the fixed capital remains idle for circulation. 

B. The unilateral continuous production method

In the unilateral continuous production method, two production processes alternate so that production is not interrupted during circulation. circulation.



We can rewrite the above figure as follows.
   

The composition of the three kinds of capital again changes over time.



Money is injected into production successively, whereas sales occur in a single stroke, leaving some money temporarily idle due to the timing gap (Marx 1978, 334, Lapavitsas 2017, 157). Marx primarily considered this method. However, Japanese Marxian economists have proposed a continuous method in which no money remains idle.  

C. Overlapping (parallel) continuous production method

In the overlapping (parallel) continuous production method, the capitalist arranges several processes in a staggered manner so that a new production process begins every week. Specifically, the total sales revenue of 600 in each period is divided among six production processes, with 100 injected into each. 

In this way, what would otherwise be a single, one-stroke circulation is transformed into a successive one, leaving no money idle. The composition of the three kinds of capital again changes over time as follows:
 

Nevertheless, c reveals that the capitalist cannot manage this process completely. Idle money arises in different forms within production and circulation, each with distinct characteristics. These differences will be discussed in Section 2.4. Before that, however, the next section examines the effect of shortening circulation under continuous production.

2.3 Relationship between Circulation Time and Initial Capital Requirement

Now, consider a case where circulation time shortens from three to two weeks. Under the assumption of continuous production, the fluctuations of the three kinds of capital are shown below. 


The number of turnovers within the same time period remains unchanged in both the 2-week and 3-week circulation cases. However, when circulation is shorter, the required amount of initial capital is lower (Marx 1978, 358). If we consider profit, profit rates would increase.
Thus, even if circulation time is shortened, total production is unchanged under continuous production. The idea that shortening circulation automatically leads to a higher periodic profit rate is somewhat misleading.
There is some literature on the adjustment of the periodic profit rate defined by Marx (Moseley 2017, Marx 2017,. De Marco 2023)

For example, Passarella and Baron (2015, p.1418) define a periodic profit rate, taking into account both the organic composition and the “temporal composition” of capital. They denote ri′ as the periodic profit rate (distinct from the profit rate in a single turnover, r) of the ith industry and express it as:

This equation appears to calculate the profit rate, adjusted for both the organic and temporal compositions of capital. However, under continuous production, the length of circulation relative to production time mainly affects the amount of initial capital required. We can therefore rewrite the expression for ri'​ as:


2.4 Difference between two types of idle money from production and circulation

As discussed in Section 2.2, if the capitalist can arrange production and circulation perfectly, no money remains idle. However, a closer look reveals the emergence of idle money.
Let us consider the simplest case, where both production time and circulation time are five weeks (Marx 1978, p. 337). In addition to this assumption, suppose that both production and circulation proceed successively. If the capitalist can make a complete arrangement, no money remains idle. The composition of the three forms of capital then changes over time as follows:

A. Idle money from production

Suppose circulation proceeds evenly, but in production different amounts of money—100, 50, 100, 150, and 100—are injected each week. Except for the initial stages, we can draw three types of capital (money, productive, and commodity) as follows:

Although Idle money appears, it is technically determined and predictable.        

B. Idle money from circulation

Now suppose that money is injected into production evenly, but weekly sales fluctuate randomly—for example, following a normal distribution. In the figure below, weekly sales follow a normal distribution with a mean of 100 and a standard deviation of 60.


Even if the average sales volume per period can be calculated, some variance always remains. When sales are faster than average (e.g., weeks 6–9 and 22–28 in the figure), idle money increases. In contrast, when sales are slower than average (e.g., weeks 3–5, 10, and 12–20), money runs short. In the example above, the maximum shortfall is about 200. To continue production smoothly, the capitalist must prepare an additional 200 units of capital in advance. The composition of the three types of capital can be drawn as follows: 

C. Brief Summary on the two types of money reserve

money capital is a kind of capital that is temporarily standing still in the form of money. It is also called other names: The fixed capital forces the capitalist to hold some reserve money to continue production. This type of reserve is called “turnover reserve” (Lapavitsas 2017, 137,165), transaction reserves or microeconomic function of circulation hoards (Saros 2008).

It should be noted that there are different types of reserve money. The first type arises predictably from successive production processes. The second type arises from unpredictable fluctuations in sales. Besides these, there are other forms of reserve money, such as funds set aside for future accumulation.

Many English-language studies on capital turnover focus on the long-term declining trend of circulation time and reserve requirements (De Marco 2022, Passarella and Baron 2015). In contrast, Unoist scholars usually focus on the uncertainty and unpredictability of circulation (Yamaguchi 1985, Lapavitsas 2017, 149, 165).

If an individual industrial capitalist tries to deal with this uncertainty of circulation on their own, they must hold a large amount of idle money. However, they may attempt to make use of their temporarily excessive idle funds, which gives rise to commercial credit between industrial capitalists.


Reference 

De Marco, G. (2022) Marx’s general rate of profit: How turnover time, accumulation and rate of surplus value affect the formation of prices of production. Review of Political Economy 34(3): 375–397.

De Marco, Guido Turnover Time and Marx's Decomposition of Profit Adjustment in the Process of Equalization.

Hidaka, Hiroshi (1977) Circulation Process of Capital [in Japanese]. Tokyo: Tokyo Daigaku Shuppankai.

Lapavitsas, Costas (2017) Marxist Monetary Theory: Collected Papers. Leiden: Brill.

Marx, Karl (1973) Grundrisse. London: Penguin Books.

Marx, Karl (1978) Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume 2. London: Penguin Books.

Marx, Karl (1981) Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume 3. London: Penguin Books.

Obata, Michiaki (2009) The Principles of Political Economy [in Japanese]. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.

Passarella, Marco Veronese and Baron, Hamid (2015) Capital’s humpback bridge: ‘Financialisation’ and the rate of turnover in Marx’s economic theory. Historical Materialism 29(4): 75–102.

Saros, Daniel E. (2014) The Turnover Continuum: A Marxist Analysis of Capitalist Fluctuations. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

Tanaka, Hideaki (1996) The Uncertainty of Circulation-process and Industrial Capital. The Hikone Ronso, No.300, pp. 155–176.

Uno, Kozo (1980) Principles of Political Economy: Theory of a Purely Capitalist Society. Brighton, Sussex: Harvester. (Marxist Theory and Contemporary Capitalism, 24)

Yamaguchi, Shigekatsu [1985] Principle of Political Economy [in Japanese]. Tokyo: Tokyo Daigaku Shuppankai.





コメント

人気の投稿